Power to the Patient: Selected Health Care Issues and Policy Solutions

Power to the Patient: Selected Health Care Issues and Policy Solutions

by Scott W. Atlas, MD
ISBN-10:
081794592X
ISBN-13:
9780817945923
Pub. Date:
02/01/2005
Publisher:
Hoover Institution Press
ISBN-10:
081794592X
ISBN-13:
9780817945923
Pub. Date:
02/01/2005
Publisher:
Hoover Institution Press
Power to the Patient: Selected Health Care Issues and Policy Solutions

Power to the Patient: Selected Health Care Issues and Policy Solutions

by Scott W. Atlas, MD
$15.0 Current price is , Original price is $15.0. You
$15.00 
  • SHIP THIS ITEM
    Qualifies for Free Shipping
  • PICK UP IN STORE
    Check Availability at Nearby Stores

Overview

The debate rages on over how to cope with the rising costs of medical care—proposed solutions range from a single payer system with a broad government control to loosely defined market-driven plans. The authors look at three key elements of health care costs and offer thoughtful, realistic suggestions to help stem the tide of rising expenses for everyone.

Product Details

ISBN-13: 9780817945923
Publisher: Hoover Institution Press
Publication date: 02/01/2005
Series: Hoover Inst Press Publication
Pages: 62
Product dimensions: 6.00(w) x 9.00(h) x 0.30(d)

About the Author

Dr. Scott W. Atlas is a senior fellow at the Hoover Institution, a professor of radiology and chief of neuroradiology at the Stanford University Medical Center, and senior fellow by courtesy at the Freeman-Spogli Institute for International Studies at Stanford.

Read an Excerpt

Power to the Patient

Selected Health Care Issues and Policy Solutions


By Scott W. Atlas

Hoover Institution Press

Copyright © 2005 Board of Trustees of the Leland Stanford Junior University
All rights reserved.
ISBN: 978-0-8179-4592-3



CHAPTER 1

Power to the Patient: The Right Choice to Control Health Care Costs


Scott W. Atlas, M.D.


Background

There is little question that health care was near the top of the list of domestic issues in the minds of voters in this past year's presidential election. Unfortunately, health care is one of the more complicated issues to address. Patients, doctors, and employers are dissatisfied with the current system, which they view as bloated, unnecessarily complex, restrictive, and at the same time increasingly costly. Proposed solutions to these problems run the gamut from loosely defined, consumer-driven plans to a single-payer system with broad government control. This diversity of opinion on health care often masks the widely shared goals of high-quality medical care, broad access, and affordability.

As the debates reverberate over how to cope with the rising cost of medical care, advanced medical technology — often but erroneously blamed as the fundamental driver for increasing medical care expenses — continues to progress at a remarkable rate. Opinion leaders in health care estimate that technology, more than any other factor in the year 2010, will have a dramatic effect on health care. Despite dissatisfaction and frustration with the current system, patients recognize that many technology-based medical innovations have been remarkably effective.

Public appreciation of the benefit from medical innovations has been accompanied by a belief that Americans are entitled to immediate and broad access to the most sophisticated health care technologies, regardless of cost. How has this unsustainable belief arisen? The third-party system of payment — the absence of direct payment from patient to doctor for most medical expenses — has shielded Americans from considerations of cost and imparted the illusion that "someone else is paying" for medical care. The forces of supply and demand have become lost amid the sea of governmental regulation and oversight in the third-party payer system. The essential step to remedy this is to change the nature of health care insurance so that patients make direct payments to their health care providers.

The United States has the costliest health care system in the world on a per capita basis. The growth of managed care in the 1990s, in an attempt to control rising health care costs, temporarily stabilized insurance premiums as well as national health care expenditures. However, average insurance premiums are once again rising by 10 to 15 percent a year, and health expenditures are predicted to increase by more than 16 percent of the gross domestic product (GDP) by 2007 and to double by 2012. Yet rising expenditures on health care are not confined to the United States. On the contrary, Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) data have shown that the universal trend in developed nations is for medical care costs to increase. It is notable that health care markets in the rest of the world are more government-controlled than in the United States.

Thanks to advances in medical care and sanitation, pharmaceutical breakthroughs, and lifestyle changes — all contributing to better health and declining birth rates — the population is aging (see figure 1.1). Since elderly patients are responsible for a large fraction of medical care costs, we seem to be headed for an unaffordable system.

Why worry about high health care costs? After all, few expenditures are more important to society. Moreover, as medical innovation continues, there may be unavoidable costs associated with their use, particularly on their first introduction. This is generally a good thing; developing more effective medical care is a major goal of modern society. In the end, more effective medical care may indeed be less costly, for example, medical instead of surgical therapy or minimally invasive treatment resulting in shorter hospital stays. Clearly, as nations become wealthier, their citizens spend more money on health care. Similarly, people spend more on houses, cars, clothes, and so on, as their income increases. The argument that high and rising health care costs are bad for people needs to be considered in context. People are spending more money on cars, houses, and Internet-related technologies — this has not necessarily been a bad thing. Insofar as people get something that they value for the extra money that they spend on medical care, it adds to their real income.


Attempts to control costs by limiting services or setting prices misalign incentives and invariably result in supply shortages — this is well documented in history, and the health care industry is no different. At the same time that the United States is leading the world into a new era in medicine with the convergence of molecular biology, medical imaging, and minimally invasive diagnosis and therapy, we have seen an alarming trend toward using technologies that are not state-of- the-art and toward reducing the availability of improved technologies with managed care penetration. These top-down regulatory approaches reduce access to advanced medical technologies and will affect our high standards and expectations of the American health care system.


How Can We Empower the Patient?

The critical focus should be on putting consumers in charge of the money and letting them make cost-conscious decisions about spending health care dollars. During this past presidential primary season, six Democratic presidential candidates have outlined proposals to broaden health insurance coverage. According to a September Commonwealth Fund publication, Democratic plans have estimated costs to the federal budget ranging from $590 billion to $6 trillion over a ten-year period. Senator Kerry's plan is estimated to add $895 billion in cost to the system over ten years. Mr. Kerry's plan also involves shifting the cost from employers and employees to taxpayers by shifting the role of the insurer from the insurance companies to the government. Expanding third-party coverage increases bureaucracy and further distances patients from paying for their own medical care. It strengthens the role of the third-party payer. This is the wrong approach. It is time to give the ownership of medical care to the patient and to expose health care to free market competition.

Out-of-pocket expenses for health care are highly important to consumers — the consideration of price is an essential part of a free market economy, and health care is no exception. A number of studies, most notably the "Rand Health Insurance Experiment" conducted from 1974 to 1982, have demonstrated that the more people have to pay for medical care without insurance reimbursement, the less they spend on total medical care. In 1960, more than 55 percent of health care costs were paid directly by the consumers of that care. Currently, third-party payers pay an unprecedented 85 percent of health care costs. This system encourages patients to neglect cost and to overspend for medical care. The separation of the patient from his medical care bills has meant less choice for the consumer: 40 percent of all employers and a full 92 percent of small employers offer only a single choice of health insurance. Yet while many nations seem to be privatizing, the American consumer is increasingly shielded from paying for medical care. Trends show that in the United States, more than in any other country, consumers paid significantly less out-of-pocket in the 1990s (see figure 1.2). This trend of decreasing out-of-pocket expenditures has continued through 2002.

The recently enacted Medicare Prescription Drug Improvement and Modernization Act of 2003 contains two extremely important provisions that have broadened coverage and empowered patients. The Medicare Act defines 1) high-deductible health plans (HDHP) and 2) tax-favored Health Savings Accounts (HSA) to be used in conjunction with a qualified high-deductible plan. The law has established that HDHPs must have a minimum deductible of $1,000 for individuals and $2,000 for families. The main effect has been to reduce the cost of health insurance by changing the role of health insurance to provide coverage for unanticipated and significant expenditures. Health insurance should not cover the small expenses of routine medical care. We do not expect our homeowner's insurance to reimburse us when the light bulbs need replacing, or the kitchen sink is clogged, or the gutters and spouts need a yearly cleaning. Likewise, we should not expect health insurance to pay for routine maintenance and minor repairs. This change will accomplish several important goals. Most important, the patient will now pay directly for most medical expenses. By paying directly, the patient will have the responsibility and decision-making authority for how the money is spent. Incentives for value consciousness enter the decision process, since the illusion that "someone else" is paying is eliminated.


Raising deductibles will clearly make health insurance more affordable, for the employer as well as the individual. Lee and Tollen reported that a combination of 30 percent coinsurance with a $1,000 deductible would reduce premiums by 44 percent. According to that study, savings in health insurance premiums would approach 50 percent by raising deductibles to $2,000. It is important to note that the cost of health insurance is reduced more by increasing out-of-pocket payments than by paring down insurance benefits. Employers paid $335 billion in health insurance premiums in 2001, and employer health expenditures have grown from 10 to 15 percent yearly since then. The high cost of health insurance has been the main contributor to the increasing number of uninsured because many employers have withdrawn health insurance from benefits packages. Of those workers who do not have health insurance, about 60 percent work for employers who do not offer this benefit.

High deductibles also will eliminate the bureaucracy and cost that accompany filing small claims. Administrative costs are projected to exceed $200 billion a year by 2012 and are rising faster than any other health care cost, aside from prescription drugs. Small claims represent a large fraction of the estimated 25 percent of total health care dollars spent on administrative tasks. Eliminating the burden of smaller claims will also markedly reduce the bureaucratic headaches of physicians, patients, and employers alike. Because the patient will pay directly for smaller claims, the patient becomes the customer. Third-party payers will be marginalized for most doctor-patient interactions. Patient and doctor satisfaction will undoubtedly improve because the physician will be caring for the customer again, restoring the patient-doctor relationship. Satisfaction with the overall system will be improved for everyone.

Paying directly for health services will also diminish the notion of entitlement. As noted earlier, an unprecedented 85 percent of health care costs are paid by third parties — insurance companies, government, or employers. Shielding consumers (patients) from directly paying doctor bills has fostered the idea that patients are entitled to all medical care, regardless of cost. Insurance coverage with near-zero deductibles has implied that health care is "free." Beyond fostering an unsustainable attitude of entitlement, it has further encouraged elevated demand, since out-of-pocket costs have been minimized. One can see the effect on cost of direct patient payment in the 15 percent of today's health care marketplace where consumers pay directly for medical care. This 15 percent direct payment part of medical care is mainly encountered at the margins of the system, such as in vision and dental care or cosmetic surgery. Costs have not risen significantly for these because patients are careful about how they spend their own money; that is, when patients pay directly, they are quite successful in holding down cost increases. A number of previous studies, most notably the Rand Health Insurance Experiment conducted from 1974 to 1982, have demonstrated that the more people have to pay for medical care without reimbursement, the less they spend on medical care. This is not a cause for hand wringing, as if patients were making "bad decisions" and foregoing essential medical care; to the contrary, it is simply an illustration of adult consumers making independent decisions that factor in cost. Why should it be any other way?

How would patients pay for their newly uncovered medical care? The Medicare Act of 2003 established a new tax-favored Health Savings Account, or HSA, as the second part of needed change in health insurance. This law allows people to deposit money for health care up to the lesser of the amount of the high deductible of the HDHP, or $2,600 for individuals or $5,250 for families. The person who owns the account, as well as others, including the employer, can contribute to the account. Deposits to the accounts would come from the difference in the cost of premiums for a low-deductible insurance policy and for the new one with a high deductible. Regulations are also outlined for the tax-free use of these accounts for qualified medical expenses and in special circumstances for other health insurance.

HSAs are designed to improve on previously established health care savings plans in significant ways. For instance, the laws for the new accounts eliminate many of the 1996 restrictions on medical savings accounts (MSAs) or similar tax-sheltered personal accounts. First, higher caps on contributions are allowed, so high deductibles can be covered. Indeed, the new contribution limits would cover what most patients spend on medical care during any single year (less than $2,000 according to survey data). A 1989 survey reported by health economists Jensen and Morlock found that nearly three-quarters of patients filed claims for less than $500 and nearly 90 percent filed claims for less than $2,000. This means nearly three of four patients would have more than $2,000 left in savings at the end of the year.

Second, the new HSAs are allowed to accumulate, tax-free, without being subject to "use it or lose it" rules. This distinguishes the new HSAs from employer-offered flexible spending accounts (FSAs), which are forfeited if they remain unused at the end of each year.

Third, HSAs are owned by the individual rather than the employer. Therefore, HSAs are portable, that is, neither tied to a specific employer nor even linked to current employment. Progress toward reducing the number of uninsured from more than 43 million Americans could be made, since many uninsured are those who have lost jobs, even temporarily. Moreover, a large pool of savings would build during years when medical expenses are relatively low.

Other significant changes should be made to the health insurance industry. For instance, residents of a state are now restricted to the insurance companies in that state for their health insurance. There needs to be a national insurance market. It ought to be possible for an insurance company to be licensed federally and to operate in all states so that the customers in different states can have the benefit of competition and a wider range of alternatives. Deregulation of the insurance industry is essential in promoting competition to benefit consumers.


The New Era of Patient Empowerment

With this purchasing power comes new authority and responsibility, coinciding with the emerging era of self-directed health care. A recent study noted a clear trend toward independent decision making by health care consumers. It found that the percentage of consumers who said they followed their doctor's recommendations without question fell from 53 percent in 2000 to only 36 percent in 2002. In contrast, the percentage of consumers who said they would ask their doctors to send them to the hospital that the patients themselves preferred now stands at 55 percent — up from 36 percent in 2000. Moreover, physicians — at 27 percent — rank only as the second most important source of information for patients, far behind the Internet, with 37 percent of consumers using the Internet to research hospitals, physicians, medical conditions, insurance plans, and other aspects of their own care.

Free market health care will create the appropriate incentives for discovering efficient ways to capitalize on the vast amount of information now on the Internet for both consumers and insurers. The asymmetry of medical information that has long been an obstacle to consumers is becoming much less important as the information becomes both widely accessible and virtually free. As access to online information about health and health insurance becomes widespread, the arguments against patient- directed health care become tenuous.


Can Consumers Make Appropriate Decisions about Health Care?

Medical test markets that require out-of-pocket purchase have clearly illustrated the effect of the free market and patient decision-making on health care. Recent examples include whole body CT screening, for which prices fell from about $1,200 to $300 over a two-year period. In fact, an interesting argument can be made for the societal benefit of the affluent in these settings — that the affluent segment of society serves as the test market for expensive medical innovations not covered by health insurance.


(Continues...)

Excerpted from Power to the Patient by Scott W. Atlas. Copyright © 2005 Board of Trustees of the Leland Stanford Junior University. Excerpted by permission of Hoover Institution Press.
All rights reserved. No part of this excerpt may be reproduced or reprinted without permission in writing from the publisher.
Excerpts are provided by Dial-A-Book Inc. solely for the personal use of visitors to this web site.

Table of Contents

Contents

Contributors,
Preface,
Acknowledgments,
1. Power to the Patient: The Right Choice to Control Health Care Costs 1 Scott W. Atlas, M.D.,
2. The Medical Liability System: Current Debates Daniel P. Kessler,
3. The Realities of the Growth in Medical Spending Mark V. Pauly,
Index,

From the B&N Reads Blog

Customer Reviews